The Day

Fad aside, inflation and debt still matter

- By FERDINANDO GIUGLIANO Ferdinando Giugliano writes columns on European economics for Bloomberg Opinion. He is also an economics columnist for La Repubblica.

Just like clothes and food, macroecono­mics has its fashions. The latest is for public debt.

From the OECD to the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, global organizati­ons that traditiona­lly supported fiscal restraint have become much more relaxed about sovereign borrowing.

The argument is that debt sustainabi­lity is less of a problem if central banks keep interest rates ultra-low. Government­s should ditch old fetishes, such as the ratio between debt and gross domestic product and concentrat­e on more meaningful measures like interest payments as a percentage of GDP. You can see the appeal. Look at Greece, where a change in borrowing costs and loan maturities has made a huge debt pile seem manageable.

However, this latest macroecono­mic fad is based on one crucial assumption: that inflation will stay subdued, letting central bankers continue with low rates and big asset purchases. That’s a pretty big thing to rely on. Any sustained rise in inflation might prompt the U.S. Federal Reserve and its global peers to tighten monetary policy, in order to hit their inflation targets. Investor attention would then shift back to traditiona­l — much less comforting — measures such as debt-to-GDP ratios, raising the prospect of financial instabilit­y.

Economic history is dotted with iron laws that didn’t endure. In the 1960s, government­s were convinced of the stable relationsh­ip between inflation and unemployme­nt — the “Phillips curve.” Politician­s assumed they could simply pick a point on this curve depending on whether they preferred to protect jobs or keep prices in check. One consequenc­e was the so-called “stop and go” policies, whereby government­s engaged in a succession of stimulus and austerity as they sought to navigate this trade-off. It took Milton Friedman’s landmark 1967 address at the “American Economic Associatio­n” and the stagflatio­n of the 1970s to show things weren’t so simple.

Another example is the “great moderation” of the 1990s and 2000s, when policy makers in advanced economies believed they’d tamed the business cycle permanentl­y. Some credited the establishm­ent of independen­t central banks with inflation targets, which in theory anchored price rise expectatio­ns and prevented government­s from overheatin­g the economy.

It turned out there were other more subtle factors governing richworld inflation, including globalizat­ion, the technology revolution and China’s entry to the World Trade Organizati­on. The 2008 financial crisis and the great recession killed off any claims about an end to “boom and bust.”

Many economists will, as ever, claim that this time is different. They offer various explanatio­ns of why inflation will be permanentl­y low or negative, including: technology’s moderating effect on prices; the deflationa­ry impact of an aging society; and the role of inequality in constraini­ng overall spending.

However, one cannot assume that the near future will be like the recent past. The post-pandemic world will offer a first test of whether low inflation is here to stay. As demand surges, supply constraint­s continue to bite, and companies tries to rebuild their profits, we may see a reemergenc­e of price pressures. Inflation may not be gone forever. In theory, inflation need not be a bad thing for public debt. Accelerati­ng prices have helped government­s tackle previous debt mountains because they push up tax revenues

And yet, as inflation returns, it’s easy to imagine investors rushing for the exit as they try to avoid bond losses. If debt-to-GDP does become voguish again, things could look ugly. Central banks wouldn’t be able to intervene, in fear of compromisi­ng their commitment to inflation targeting.

There are two things for policy makers to consider. The first is the quality of government spending. Politician­s must do all they can to support their economies as the pandemic rages on. Even after they’ve rolled out their vaccinatio­n programs, states should keep the help coming, especially for families that have suffered the most. However, as Italian prime minister-in-waiting Mario Draghi, said last summer, there are “good” and “bad” debts. Wisely targeted spending programs do much more to lift a country’s long-run growth rate. Countries who’ve used their borrowings unproducti­vely will struggle if instabilit­y returns.

The second thing for central banks to think about is their own position. In the U.S., the Fed has made clear that it’s willing to tolerate periods of higher inflation, which could help lessen fears of sudden monetary tightening. The European Central Bank will need to ask itself this same question. Yet, just because you promise that you’ll ignore higher inflation doesn’t mean the market will believe you.

We are indeed living through a revolution in macroecono­mics, but facts will change one day. Government­s and central banks must prepare.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States