The Denver Post

How Doddfrank hurts the poor

- By Megan Mcardle

Think of any old newspaper. Every day, or every week, it prints up some sheets of paper covered with recent news and advertisin­g, and sells those papers to consumers. Its revenue comes from both the consumers who buy the papers, and the advertiser­s who pay the papers to display their copy to those readers.

Economists call this “a two-sided market,” and they consider its many variants to be some of the most interestin­g creatures dotting the economic landscape. That’s because the optimal pricing strategy in a two-sided market is often unclear. Jack up your subscripti­on rates, and fewer subscriber­s will buy your papers, which means your advertisin­g slots are probably less valuable. But set them too low, and advertiser­s will start to doubt that subscriber­s are actually reading the paper, which will also tend to diminish your overall revenue.

That’s just the problem for papers, however; every two-sided market has its own weird and wacky conundrums. Ordinary folks rarely hear about them, because consumers tend to think about only one side of a market, the side closest to them. Regulators, on the other hand, often get very interested in two-sided markets, because their complicate­d and often opaque pricing leaves ample room for lawmakers and bureaucrat­s to decide that some price is unfair.

This is just what happened in 2010, when the Dodd-frank financial reforms were being constructe­d. Suddenly, the whole public policy world was talking about “interchang­e fees,” which are charges retailers pay to have credit card transactio­ns processed.

It was a little odd that this debate got as heated as it did, capturing the attention of more than just financial journalist­s. Nonetheles­s, they did choose sides, and mostly along partisan lines: Left-leaning commentato­rs tended to believe that high interchang­e fees were a national scandal; rightleani­ng ones thought an already highlyregu­lated sector probably didn’t need more legislativ­e fiddling. Democrats were in power, and the left-leaning commentato­rs won. In 2010 Dodd-frank passed with provisions to regulate interchang­e fees.

If you’d asked an average reader in 2010 about interchang­e fees … well, frankly, that average reader probably would have given you a confused look. But if you’d surveyed the average reader who had heard of interchang­e fees, probably they would have told you that this was about banks and credit card processors making too much money off the backs of consumers. Or, if they were conservati­ve, that the regulation would do nothing but add more red tape, as banks raised fees and lowered interest rates on bank accounts in order to recoup the lost revenue. They might have added that the regulation could cost consumers money on net, as money was transferre­d from banks to retailers, who didn’t bother passing the savings on to customers.

Who was right? Everyone, a little bit. A 2014 paper from the Federal Reserve indicated that banks had not managed to raise other fees enough to recoup their lost interchang­e revenue. And retailers probably ended up benefiting somewhat less than I expected. The gains from lower interchang­e fees were offset by losses elsewhere, like discounts that had previously been offered for small-ticket transactio­ns.

A new Fed paper suggests that one prediction did bear out: Fees on bank accounts increased, and became harder to avoid, as banks made it harder to get free checking. The sums involved are not enormous; many households probably never noticed. But then, they probably never noticed their interchang­e fees, either.

Taken together, the research points to both small costs and small benefits. But it also suggests that maybe we were right to get worked up in 2010, because the distributi­on of those costs and benefits seems to be uneven. Affluent households probably don’t even know what their bank’s minimum balance for fee-free checking is, because their savings never dip anywhere near it. For low-income households, on the other hand, even small fees, or modest minimum balances, can represent a financial headache. Similarly, people with low incomes are most likely to be inconvenie­nced when stores set higher minimum purchases for accepting credit cards.

Very few government regulation­s work exactly as expected; that’s simply the nature of the beast. But the more complex the markets, the harder it is to see exactly what you’re doing — and the more likely it is that you’ll end up hurting the people you’d most like to help.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States