The Denver Post

Fed’s coronaviru­s rescues invite bigger bailouts

- By Bill Dudley Bloomberg Opinion

The Federal Reserve has responded aggressive­ly to market strains and the sharp drop in the economy caused by the coronaviru­s pandemic. The central bank cut short-term interest rates nearly to zero, bought hundreds of billions of dollars of Treasuries and mortgage-backed securities and it introduced a plethora of special liquidity facilities designed to support markets. The Fed’s actions have largely worked, easing financial conditions and enabling corporatio­ns and municipali­ties to borrow in the U.S. debt markets. If I were in the Fed’s shoes, I would have pushed for the same forceful interventi­ons.

That said, the Fed’s actions have a cost because they tend to encourage risky behavior that we want to avoid — a problem known as moral hazard. Not all of those who got help were blameless.

Consider, for example, the Fed’s enormous purchases of Treasuries as trading began to seize up. It was, in fact, a backdoor bailout of highly leveraged hedge funds that were caught in an untenable trade of being long cash Treasuries and short Treasury futures. When volatility was low, these positions could be leveraged up to generate attractive returns. But when the pandemic hit and volatility soared and those trades lost value, margin lenders who financed the positions asked for more equity. This led to fire sales, with many sellers and few buyers. The result was a climb in Treasury yields, a widening in bid-offer spreads and a sharp drop in liquidity in what is normally the most liquid market in the world.

The Fed decided that the risk of a dysfunctio­nal Treasury market was bigger than the downside of bailing out the leveraged hedge funds. Although the Fed helped stabilize the Treasury market, it also made it possible for the hedge funds to avoid bearing the full costs of their risky decisions.

The story isn’t much different in the mortgage-debt market. As volatility soared, real-estate investment trusts that invest in mortgage-backed securities were forced sellers as they struggled to meet margin calls. Again, the Fed purchases limited their losses.

Heavily indebted corporatio­n also got a helping hand. This is significan­t because many corporatio­ns took on lots of debt by choice. The Fed’s response was to set up corporate bond facilities, limiting the fall in lower-rated corporate debt prices and keeping these markets accessible for companies that needed to raise funds. These actions also protected investors in high-yield mutual-bond funds. Had the funds been forced to sell amid plunging prices to meet large redemption­s, this could have set off a chain reaction. Both the asset managers and the retail investors who bought shares in these junk-bond funds escaped bearing the cost of their actions.

So why should we care that some not-so-innocent parties were bailed out by the Fed? Because it brings us back to moralhazar­d problem: investors win during good times (they can assume more risk and earn higher returns) while the Fed and the U.S. Treasury (ultimately taxpayers) assume part of the downside risks when there is trouble in financial markets. This is likely to encourage even greater risk-taking down the road.

This doesn’t seem to be a good road to stay on. But getting off it is very difficult. After all, no one wants to risk a depression in order to teach hedge funds, mortgage REITs or mutual-fund investors a lesson.

So what can be done about moral hazard?

First, structural weaknesses in financial markets need to be fixed in peacetime, not in the middle of a crisis. One obvious example would be to prohibit mutual funds from offering liquidity on-demand when the assets they hold are illiquid. If you are investing in risky assets, you shouldn’t need to have overnight liquidity.

Second, determine what is systemic — in other words, what is potentiall­y a large enough threat to financial markets and the economy. If something is systemic, as our banking system is, then there is a strong case that it needs to be regulated. That is why banks are subject to liquidity and capital requiremen­ts, and why they provide deposit insurance and pay premiums for it.

Third, one might consider requiring systemic non-bank financial institutio­ns and illiquid investment funds to buy Fed liquidity insurance.

None of these changes would be easy to implement. Unfortunat­ely, when the crisis fades, the pressure to adopt reforms will wane. Neverthele­ss, the moral hazard issue needs to be debated and addressed. Big crises seem to be occurring more often and Fed interventi­ons are growing ever bigger in size and broader in scope. Whatever you thought was the size of the moral-hazard problem before, now it’s gotten even larger.

 ??  ?? Fred Fletcher works as a public safety consultant, trainer, and speaker. Previously, he served as chief of police in Chattanoog­a, Tenn., and Rockport, Texas. He is a resident of Woodland Park.
Fred Fletcher works as a public safety consultant, trainer, and speaker. Previously, he served as chief of police in Chattanoog­a, Tenn., and Rockport, Texas. He is a resident of Woodland Park.
 ??  ?? Bill Dudley is a senior research scholar at Princeton University’s Center for Economic Policy Studies.
Bill Dudley is a senior research scholar at Princeton University’s Center for Economic Policy Studies.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States