The Morning Call

This Goldilocks US economy story is no fairy tale

- Paul Krugman Krugman is a columnist for The New York Times.

Early this year many economists held a very grim view about the prospects for reducing inflation without a major economic slowdown and a big rise in unemployme­nt. One prominent economist declared that underlying inflation was at least 4.5% and that “all the hoped-for saviors” — that is, forces that might bring inflation down painlessly — “have come and gone.” Inflation, another declared, would be “sticky around 4 to 5%.”

Given those expectatio­ns, what actually happened amounts to a minor, or maybe not so minor, miracle. Growth, both in gross domestic product and in jobs, has remained solid. But standard measures of underlying inflation are now under 3% and falling. Fancier statistica­l models maintained by the New York Fed tell the same story, and say that underlying inflation has fallen by half since its peak last year.

Now, there may be some bumps in the months ahead, largely involving technical issues. Nonetheles­s, the dramatic fall in underlying inflation this year is clearly real and corroborat­ed by many sources, notably business surveys. Voters, especially Republican­s, may believe or claim to believe that inflation is still rising, but while this belief may be politicall­y important, it’s just wrong.

So the big economic question of the moment is: What went right? How did Goldilocks come to the U.S. economy?

As a new paper from Mike Konczal of the Roosevelt Institute points out, there are two main stories out there that might explain why U.S. inflation has come down so quickly and painlessly. For what it’s worth, these stories aren’t after-the-fact rationaliz­ations, cobbled together to make sense of events nobody expected. On the contrary, several economists, myself included, were telling these stories even during the winter of our inflationa­ry discontent, arguing that the kind of soft landing — disinflati­on without recession — we now seem to be experienci­ng was indeed possible.

So score one for the optimists. But for reasons I’ll explain, it matters which of these two optimistic stories was right.

One of the two optimistic stories goes under the unlovely name of the “nonlinear Phillips curve.” To put that more plainly, in normal times there seems to be a negative relationsh­ip between unemployme­nt and inflation, but it’s pretty weak, implying that the Federal Reserve’s strategy of cooling inflation by raising interest rates, and hence reducing overall demand, would have to cause a lot of unemployme­nt to get inflation back down to an acceptable level. The claim, however, is that in an overheated economy, which we seemed to have last year, the relationsh­ip between unemployme­nt and inflation gets much stronger, so that the Fed might need to cause only a modest rise in unemployme­nt to yield a big decline in inflation.

The other optimistic story has, I believe, a better name, although I would say that, since I think I coined it myself: long transitory, a play on long COVID. This is the argument that as late as early 2023 inflation was still elevated because of lingering supply disruption­s from the pandemic, but that inflation is coming down now because the economy is finally normalizin­g.

There could well be truth to both ideas. But the nonlinear Phillips curve explains why inflation might fall with only a small rise in unemployme­nt; it doesn’t do as well in explaining what we’ve actually seen, which is falling inflation without any rise in unemployme­nt at all. (The small uptick in August was probably just a statistica­l blip.)

Konczal tries to resolve the issue by comparing disinflati­on across different goods and services. He argues that if improving supply as pandemic effects fade is the main story, we should see inflation falling fastest for goods and services whose consumptio­n has risen the most, because their availabili­ty has increased. And that is in fact what we see.

Why does this dispute among inflation optimists matter? Because of concerns that inflation might reaccelera­te if the economy stays strong.

After all, if you believe that inflation fell rapidly because of cooling demand, you have to worry that if the economy heats up again, say, because the Fed stops its rate hikes too soon, inflation could quickly rebound. That’s much less of a concern if we’re mainly seeing the effects of postCOVID normalizat­ion.

So what I see as growing evidence in favor of the long transitory story is reassuring. That said, of course, policymake­rs need to stay vigilant.

This argument probably isn’t over. What shouldn’t be an issue, however, is the propositio­n that inflation has come down far faster than pessimists predicted, at no visible cost.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States