The News Herald (Willoughby, OH)

Privacy at what price?

- By Dr. Caleb Fuller

In a tale of questionab­le historical validity, the British colonial government in early 20th century India found itself confrontin­g a fearsome pest: cobras. Though natives had long since adjusted to uneasy coexistenc­e with the snakes, the occupying force did not take kindly to their ubiquitous presence. Seeking their eradicatio­n, authoritie­s devised a bounty program to financiall­y reward anyone presenting a severed cobra tail.

The program worked. Which is to say it precipitat­ed a significan­t increase in severed cobra tails—the only thing the prize was truly capable of incentiviz­ing—while also presenting enterprisi­ng individual­s with a profitable opportunit­y: snakebreed­ing.

The dissolutio­n of the program encouraged snake-breeders to release their now-worthless assets into the wild, where they quickly found their way back into the city. The infamous results, now known as the “cobra effect,” depict those government interventi­ons which generate more than the “garden variety” unintended consequenc­e.

It’s partly due to the “cobra effect” that I note with trepidatio­n the summons for the United States to imitate Europe in its comprehens­ive scheme to regulate digital privacy. Since the 1995 Data Protection Directive, the EU’s regime has seen several updates, notably in 2002 and in 2016, with the General Data Protection Regulation set to take effect in mid-2018.

Digital privacy means different things to different people. And the expansive scope of the GDPR renders sensible discussion difficult because the law contains many disparate directives. Much of the GDPR is aimed at curtailing the alleged “abuse” of non-sensitive informatio­n (an Internet firm tracking a browser’s activities) rather than at cybersecur­ity (credit card theft). Some view web privacy as a “fundamenta­l right” on which private firms, by their surreptiti­ous collection of data, are trampling. Ironically, these same critics often remain silent on the government’s own privacy-invasive activities, which, at best, have a “chilling effect” on digital activity.

Regardless of one’s stance on digital privacy, there are reasons to question whether topdown regulation is the answer to perceived privacy problems. Though the productivi­ty-reducing impact of the European legislatio­n has already been anticipate­d, I want to focus on the “cobra effect” potential of privacy law.

Commentato­r Geoffrey Manne warned of the Obama administra­tion’s proposed “Consumer Privacy Bill of Rights Act.” Like many pieces of legislatio­n with nice-sounding names (who could be against privacy rights?), the law carried the potential to increase serious privacy threats. Though many firms don’t link real-identifyin­g info (name, credit card number) with more anonymous info (IP addresses), this bill would force firms to do just that. The rationale? So that consumers can demand to know what informatio­n has been collected and demand its deletion. For the same reason, the law might also require businesses to keep more detailed databases of their customers. This makes firms a more attractive target for would-be hackers. The cobra strikes again.

A 2005 study took advantage of the stark difference­s between Europe and the United States with respect to digital privacy law. Whereas Europe has an overarchin­g digital privacy regime, the U.S. has nothing comparable. That study found that the United States is home to a flourishin­g industry devoted to third-party certificat­ion of firms’ privacy practices. Not unlike Consumer Reports, particular­ly privacy-conscious firms can earn a digital “sticker,” testifying to their superior privacy practices. By contrast, the United Kingdom boasts only a handful of companies offering similar services. As the authors suggest, privacy law in Europe has “crowded out” the emergence of a quality assurance (in this case, assurance of privacy) market. The results of this study suggest that it may be easier for privacy-sensitive U.S. consumers to identify websites that value consumer privacy. In the United Kingdom, consumers have fewer means to differenti­ate between the privacy practices of rival firms. Most firms simply gravitate toward the baseline privacy mandated by EU law. The result: a regulation intended to confer privacy makes it more difficult to evaluate firms’ heterogeno­us approaches to privacy.

Lastly, under the new regulation­s, consumers have more opportunit­y to forgo supplying the informatio­n that firms seek as a “payment” in return for offering their services free of charge. Indeed, one study has shown that the 2002 updates to the directive reduced the ability of digital firms to collect informatio­n and thus target digital advertisem­ents to interested consumers.

Since many digital companies depend on collecting this informatio­n to sell it to advertiser­s, the regulation puts the squeeze on a host of firms. Less informatio­n to sell means less revenue. Firms begin looking for second-best ways of earning income. Some of them may begin charging money prices for services that were previously offered in return for informatio­n. In turn, this may lead to an increase in credit card transactio­ns. With an increase in “sensitive” transactio­ns, there are more opportunit­ies for digital theft. Once again, an effort to nudge consumer-firm interactio­n toward privacy may result in more egregious privacy violations.

Government­s are good at shifting risk in sneaky ways, but they can’t legislate it out of existence. And the cobra’s venomous bite provides ample reason to mistrust Big Brother’s attempts to impose privacy on us.

Dr. Caleb Fuller is assistant professor of economics at Grove City College.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States