The Sentinel-Record

Warren wasn’t first one to propose wealth tax

- Copyright 2019, Washington Post Writers group Catherine Rampell

A brash political candidate forms a presidenti­al explorator­y committee. Almost immediatel­y, the candidate announces a controvers­ial policy: a wealth tax on the ultrarich.

Just one and a half pages long, the proposal is met with some cheers but lots of jeers — about its constituti­onality, feasibilit­y, fairness. Rightwing pundits bemoan the appeal to class warfare.

That candidate?

Donald Trump, in 1999, pursuing the Reform Party nomination. Everything old is new again.

Last week, Sen. Elizabeth Warren,

D-Mass., now exploring a presidenti­al run, proposed her own wealth tax. Warren’s proposal is constructe­d differentl­y than

Trump’s was — his was a onetime levy, hers is annual — but the reception has been similar.

The case for such a tax has only grown stronger over time, even if the way Warren goes about it could stand to be improved.

Over several decades, U.S. policies have facilitate­d a systematic upward redistribu­tion of wealth.

Congress has slashed taxes overall, but especially on the rich; reduced or eliminated brackets that applied only to the tippy-top income percentile­s, making the tax code less progressiv­e at the top; neutered the estate tax; cut rates on long-term capital gains; added “Inception”-like loopholes within loopholes, which disproport­ionately benefit taxpayers with the sophistica­tion and resources to game the system; and gutted the Internal Revenue Service, which catches these tax dodgers.

All of these deliberate choices helped the richest households to accumulate more wealth and make that wealth more persistent across generation­s.

They have also contribute­d to the government’s growing revenue shortfall. If you want to patch deficits, go where the money is — increasing­ly, at the very top.

We should think of a wealth tax as a way to correct the mistakes of the past.

It’s hard to unwind 40 years of bad tax policy by jacking up marginal rates on ordinary income alone. The Trump family makes a good poster child for why: Adding a new 70 percent marginal tax rate on income above $10 million, for instance, would barely dent the accumulate­d wealth passed down — much of it untaxed — from Fred Trump to Donald to Ivanka and subsequent generation­s.

There are some problems with a straightfo­rward wealth tax, however. For starters, its constituti­onality is unclear, given the requiremen­t that “direct” taxes be apportione­d among the states. Some legal scholars argue that a wealth tax would hold up to a constituti­onal challenge. But with the current Supreme Court, that’s far from guaranteed.

There are other hitches, too, some specific to Warren’s (relatively bare-bones) formulatio­n: a 2 percent annual tax on a household’s wealth above $50 million, with the rate rising to 3 percent on any wealth above $1 billion. Some obvious ways to game that $50 million threshold trigger include strategic divorce, within-family transfers and tricks for deflating valuations.

Plus, annually enforcing such a system would be an administra­tive nightmare for the government — and a feast for accountant­s, tax attorneys and the like. As tax practition­ers who’ve appraised large estates could tell you, mark-to-market valuations of highly illiquid assets (closely held businesses, rare works of art) are easily manipulate­d.

Warren proposes handling this by beefing up tax enforcemen­t, through greater IRS funding, for example. That’s something we should absolutely do anyway, but it’s not clear manpower alone would be enough.

These problems are not insurmount­able, however. As tax experts such as University of Chicago law professor Daniel Hemel have suggested, you could reconfigur­e parts of the income tax to create something that effectivel­y operates like Warren’s wealth tax, except with fewer constituti­onal or administra­tive headaches.

Congress could set the tax rate on long-term capital gains to match that of ordinary income. It could shore up the estate tax and repeal the “stepped-up basis” that allows unrealized capital gains to go untaxed when a person dies.

Raising the capital-gains rate might encourage rich people to delay sales of assets. But Congress could claw back these deferral benefits, through something called a retrospect­ive wealth tax. It’s a bit complicate­d, but it’s like charging interest for the years you held an asset before selling it (or dying). Nobel laureate William Vickrey proposed a version of this 80 years ago, and it has since been tweaked by Alan Auerbach and David Bradford. Despite the name, such a tax could still be administer­ed through the income-tax system, reducing the risk of constituti­onal challenge.

Other possible iterations are worth considerin­g, too. Let’s hope Warren’s proposal produces at least a vigorous, good-faith debate about the best and fairest ways to redress the policy errors of past generation­s.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States