The Sentinel-Record

Selective retreat from Chinese trade makes sense

- Amitrajeet A. Batabyal AP’s The Conversati­on Arthur J. Gosnell is a professor of Economics, Rochester Institute of Technology. The Conversati­on is an independen­t and nonprofit source of news, analysis and commentary from academic experts.

Trade tensions and mistrust are escalating between the U.S. and China. Soon after U.S. Secretary of State Mike Pompeo announced that China recommitte­d to its January trade deal obligation­s after a face-to-face meeting with Beijing’s top diplomat on June 17, he upbraided the country for using disinforma­tion to drive a wedge between Europe and the U.S. President Trump, meanwhile, is attempting to use his tough stance with Beijing as a foreign policy selling point.

Behind the headlines and politics, a basic question remains: How much benefit is the U.S. getting out of its trade relationsh­ip with China? As a scholar in internatio­nal trade theory and policy, I believe that answer must be looked at through a wider lens than just economics – one that includes national security.

A model where both countries benefit

Economists have long agreed that free internatio­nal trade can benefit countries when it is based on the principle of comparativ­e advantage. Popularize­d by the English economist David Ricardo, this means that countries should export goods they can make more efficientl­y and less expensivel­y to other countries, and import goods the other country can make more efficientl­y.

Free trade theory states that such trade, as opposed to trade that uses tariffs and quotas, makes nations better off. That’s because it creates overall benefits for countries. There may still be individual losers in certain industries, but overall, all nations are deemed winners.

It is, in theory, possible to take some of the winners’ gains in a nation and give it to that country’s losers, and still have some surplus left over. The “losers” are typically the industries that compete with imports and its workers.

The practical problem with this line of reasoning is that the U.S. typically either does not make compensato­ry payments to the losers from trade or, when it does, the payments are puny. Uncle Sam provides assistance to those who lose out from free trade via the Department of Labor’s Trade Adjustment Assistance program.

As long as workers displaced by internatio­nal trade enroll in a job training program, the adjustment assistance provides relocation assistance, subsidized health insurance and extended unemployme­nt benefits. However, the program has been severely criticized by workers themselves, even earning the nickname “burial insurance,” as in arriving just in time to bury the victims.

Credible statistics are hard to come by to show the true monetary gains from trade. However, the economists Arnaud Costinot and Andres Rodriguez-Clare have shed valuable light on this question. Their research shows that the share of spending on imports in the U.S. is smaller than other countries. That is in large part because the U.S. is a large country, and most trade occurs within the nation.

Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare point out that about 8 cents out of every dollar spent in the U.S. is spent on imports.

We can now ask: How much would it cost U.S. consumers if the country stopped trade with other nations? The answer to this question is known as the welfare cost of zero trade or, equivalent­ly, the welfare gains from trade.

Because the U.S. doesn’t trade that much, the welfare gains from internatio­nal trade in the U.S. are smaller than in many other countries. Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare estimate these gains from all trade for the U.S. range from 2% to 8% of gross domestic product.

For a large and diversifie­d nation such as the U.S., this is relatively small. The reason is that the share of all U.S. spending that goes to imports is around 6%-8%. Put differentl­y, the U.S. is a lot less reliant on imports than many other more trade-reliant countries. To compare, Belgium – a much smaller but more trade-reliant nation – spends 30% on imports.

If the U.S. were to move to economic self-sufficienc­y by stopping all trade with other nations, then it would be worse off, but based on the previous research, not dramatical­ly so.

While that may not be practical overall, it is worth looking at it through the lens of U.S.-China trade specifical­ly.

What COVID-19 shows us

To manage the outbreak of the coronaviru­s, the Chinese government closed large numbers of factories and ports. Entire cities and even provinces were locked down. These stringent measures have caused significan­t disruption­s to U.S. firms with China-only supply chains. Even more significan­t is the extent to which the U.S. is dependent on China for vital goods such as medicines.

More generally, in 2018, China supplied about 42% of the world’s exports of personal protective equipment. Almost 75% of Italy’s imported blood thinners came from China, and so did 60% of the ingredient­s for antibiotic­s imported by Japan.

This dependence poses a national security threat. For example, if relations with China were to deteriorat­e further, then China could hold back shipping on, for instance, vital pharmaceut­ical ingredient­s. China has been known to abuse its market power.

Most standard economic analyses about the gains and losses from trade typically do not take national security issues into account. However, some research exists on how to intervene in an economy to attain “noneconomi­c objectives.” The fact that trade can be weaponized was alluded to by the economist Adam Smith, who observed in 1776 that national security can trump free trade concerns.

This is because if certain goods are necessary for national security, then free trade in these goods may reduce a nation’s capacity to produce the goods, thereby making them scarce should a national emergency arise.

Given the increasing tensions and complexiti­es around trade with China, I believe it may be time to selectivel­y retreat from trading with the Chinese over supplies critical to national security. Such a retreat will have to involve, among other controls, setting procuremen­t rules so that health care providers buy U.S. products, reducing and ideally eliminatin­g the dependence on China-only supply chains, and monitoring cross-border mergers and acquisitio­ns. In other words, we would still have globalizat­ion, but with diminished Chinese influence.

This will be difficult to implement on a practical level given the close relationsh­ips the U.S. markets have with China – and the roughly US$539.5 billion in goods it imports each year. But short-term pain from the transition may well result in longterm gain from protecting national security.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States