The Sun (Lowell)

AI is likely to create more jobs than it kills

- By Clive Crook Bloomberg Opinion

Artificial intelligen­ce holds farreachin­g consequenc­es for modern economies. Many of the jobs we are asked to do will change; a lot of them might disappear altogether. Facing this existentia­l upheaval, experts advise that smart AI regulation will be needed — well, who could object to smart regulation? But the forms it should take, its methods and even its purposes, are unclear.

A good start might be to frame the problem more carefully. Easier said than done, perhaps, because AI is in many respects not technologi­cal progress as usual. Even so, earlier technologi­cal revolution­s have relevant lessons. One worth pondering concerns the so-called “lump of labor.”

The lump-of-labor fallacy is surely the most thoroughly debunked — yet most impressive­ly tenacious — misconcept­ion in economics. The idea is that there’s only so much work to go around. If a faster, cheaper way of doing this fixed quantity of work arises, jobs must disappear. Machines are therefore a threat. Mechanized farming laid waste to agricultur­al labor, factory automation destroyed manufactur­ing employment, and now AI is coming for service-sector workers. Just as before, the result will be mass unemployme­nt and, for swaths of the labor force, lower wages and collapsing living standards.

Except that this last part has always turned out to be wrong. These epochal economic transforma­tions did cause unemployme­nt. Jobs disappeare­d, workers were displaced and victims had to bear real costs. But aggregate employment kept growing and living standards soared. Why? Because far from being fixed, the quantity of work needing to be done proved to be infinitely expandable.

The same will be true of AI. There are two main paths to higher employment after this kind of innovation. The most appealing possibilit­y is that AI helps firms to sell more. The technology makes their workers more productive, but their business grows faster than their workers’ productivi­ty, so they end up hiring more people. Unlikely, you think? Consider what might prove to be the more typical case — firms make more money simply by replacing workers with AI. That decrease in jobs might still be matched by freshly minted tasks in other firms selling new, possibly Ai-enabled, goods and services.

Put simply, technology doesn’t just change the economy’s supply side; it also creates new demand. The innovation that transforme­d farming and manufactur­ing created markets for entirely new products, adding to the amount of work needing to be done. Many

of those products would have been difficult even to imagine a decade or two before they came to market. Twenty years ago I never thought I’d need a supercompu­ter in my pocket. Many of the services that this technology has enabled were equally hard to foresee. Today, countless people are well paid and overworked (have you noticed there’s a labor shortage?) producing goods and services I never knew I’d want.

This way of thinking suggests a couple of policy prescripti­ons. One is to be cautious about proposals to direct innovation to support the creation of new tasks as opposed to merely automating existing ones out of existence. Many of the tasks we might want or need are impossible to predict; mere automation, at one or more removes, is itself capable of creating new demand and hence new work. In

general, we should welcome and encourage innovation, not fear it; even if it’s “labor-saving” in the short term, it’s likely to raise wages and living standards in due course.

Second, the main economic challenge posed by AI is not how to avoid persistent mass unemployme­nt; it’s how to ease the effects of dislocatio­n. This argues for a stronger safety net, wider participat­ion in the ownership of capital, fewer frictions in labor markets (pointless occupation­al licensing is top of that list) and fresh attention to vocational training. If these seem like standard neoliberal remedies, that’s because they are. They’ve fallen short in the past not because they’re ill-suited to the role, but because they’ve been too meekly applied.

One innovation likely to be crucial if societies are to capitalize on this transition is “microcrede­ntials.” These are modules of training that can be bundled into a “macro-credential” such as a degree; they can also denote specific

vocational skills, and in that form lubricate mid- or late-career jobto-job mobility. In building out this idea of lifelong learning, companies and colleges will have to take the initiative, but public policy can promote and coordinate their efforts, improving accreditat­ion and helping would-be students find the right offerings. The range of choices in the US is already vast — but completely bewilderin­g. The European Commission and others are aiming for a more systematic and supportive approach; Singapore, predictabl­y, seems to have taken this furthest.

The challenges AI poses go far beyond the jobs market, but that domain is crucial. In this realm, at least, there’s more cause for optimism than alarm — and better policies could vastly improve the odds of success.

(Clive Crook is a Bloomberg Opinion columnist and member of the editorial board covering economics. Previously, he was deputy editor of the Economist and chief Washington commentato­r for the Financial Times.)

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States