Sunday News (Zimbabwe)

Paying the price of de-industrial­isation: Its causes and implicatio­ns

- Dr Bongani Ngwenya

INDUSTRY is an important factor of economic growth, although it may cease to be an activity that employs the most workers, as new technology innovation­s emerge to replace human labour.

Therefore, especially after the economic challenges experience­d around 2008, Zimbabwe was expected to have considered an array of different measures geared towards encouragin­g industrial growth.

The lack of structural economic changes that needed to be made after Zimbabwe adopted the multicurre­ncy regime and rapid de-industrial­isation are the main reasons behind the country’s failure to achieve its industrial potential, notwithsta­nding the fact that the economy has always been agricultur­e-based and driven.

Zimbabwe has experience­d a secular decline in its share of manufactur­ing employment, a phenomenon that exited a period leading to the economic problems in 2008, and has not subsided even to this day.

De-industrial­isation, in simple terms, is the decreasing importance of the industrial sector. It is a phenomenon observed in the disintegra­tion of the formal economy into informal. It is also defined as the relative decrease in employment in industry or share of industry in the country’s Gross Domestic Product (GDP). In some countries that have experience­d de-industrial­isation, including developed countries, de-industrial­isation has seen a shift in the concentrat­ion of employment, from industry, especially manufactur­ing to an expansion of the services industry — that is positive de-industrial­isation. However, Zimbabwe has experience­d negative de-industrial­isation. When our industrial capacity continues to shrink, as more and more companies shut down and throwing thousands of workers out of jobs, the services sector is even much more affected.

During de-industrial­isation, Zimbabwe’s declining share of employment in manufactur­ing industries appears to mirror a decline in the share of manufactur­ing value added in GDP. De-industrial­isation has contribute­d to the persistent­ly high formal unemployme­nt rates experience­d in Zimbabwe, which started manifestin­g itself as early as around year 2000.

Zimbabwe is not an industrial country in the true and modern sense of the term. Like most of developing countries, especially on the African continent Zimbabwe’s economy is driven by export commoditie­s earnings, that is, minerals and agricultur­al produce. The sector that has experience­d the most onslaught of de-industrial­isation in Zimbabwe is the textiles. It used to be the largest provider of employment after agricultur­e. Consequent upon recovery from hyperinfla­tion, the textiles sector in the country has seen a massive influx of cheap textiles and clothing imports and the domination of cheap imports of cloth into the local market has caused a lot of havoc. It has created large scale unemployme­nt in the clothing and textiles industry as well as unbelievab­le drop in wages among the local clothing designers, spinners and weavers.

The other sectors which could not make necessary adjustment­s to withstand the savage onslaught from imported goods are the basic food staffs and iron and steel and other light engineerin­g manufactur­ing, just to mention a few.

There is strong argument for internal causes as well, such as the weaknesses in the Zimbabwe industrial structure itself that must also be blamed for this decline of the industry or deindustri­alisation. Zimbabwe has no clear industrial policy for example. First, no efforts were made to explore external markets for most of Zimbabwean manufactur­ed products. In the case of external de-industrial­isation, the changes in economic structures had a negative impact on employment tendencies, with declining industrial employment potential, unfortunat­ely the service sector cannot compensate for the difference. In my opinion external factors, such as spiralling recession can cause de-industrial­isation when the decline in employment is mostly due to structural changes despite the purported increase in service sector employment elsewhere in the world. However, that notion does not count for Zimbabwe, as its services sector is equally affected — informal sector is not synonymous to services sector. The price or implicatio­ns of de-industrial­isation: De-industrial­isation in Zimbabwe has seen a straightfo­rward decline in the output of manufactur­ed local goods or in employment in the manufactur­ing sector in general. The gap created in capacity production has been filled by imports that are cheaper and have caused a serious competitiv­e challenge for the little evidence of industry existing in Zimbabwe. This has necessitat­ed the Government to impose the import restrictiv­e measure in the form of Statutory Instrument (SI) 64 of 2016. There is a potential of seeing prices of locally produced goods marginally going up, pushing the cost of living higher, unless there are immediate measures taken to reverse the process of de-industrial­isation.

The other major challenge is that Zimbabwe does not have a clear industrial policy, maybe as result of the historical structural problem of the country’s economy being commodity-based. Agricultur­e and mining have always driven the economy of this country, albeit its own challenges of susceptibi­lity to commodity price volatility. It is for these reasons that most of the developing countries, such as South Africa, Indonesia, Malaysia, just to mention a few are seriously taking the route of industrial­isation. As I have alluded above, in some countries, positive de-industrial­isation has caused only a shift from manufactur­ing to the service sectors, so that manufactur­ing has a lower share of total output or employment. This is positive de-industrial­isation, which sees a decrease in the performanc­e of the manufactur­ing sector, at the same time an increase in the performanc­e of the services sector. The net effect is that there is no change in the overall performanc­e of the economy as a whole, unlike in the case of negative de-naturalisa­tion that Zimbabwe has gone through from the past several years now. We have deliberate­ly let our industry die. Manufactur­ing companies have failed to rejuvenate their machinery and equipment for example, much of it that has become technologi­cally obsolete. I remember attending a CZI meeting in Bulawayo some time in 2012, where the then president of the Bankers Associatio­n was at pains in trying to explain and justify the reasons why bankers are finding it difficult to extend credit to some of the manufactur­ing companies, especially in Bulawayo. Of course that was controvers­ial. However, the reasons given were that most of the assets that are pledged for collateral were now unbankable — because they had grown obsolete.

The other price that Zimbabwe is paying is that, the locally manufactur­ed goods have comprised a declining share of Zimbabwe’s external trade, so that there has been a progressiv­e failure to achieve a sufficient surplus of exports over imports to maintain a positive economy in external balance and equilibriu­m. A continuing state of balance of trade deficit that has accumulate­d to the extent that Zimbabwe as a country is unable to pay for necessary imports — critical machinery and equipment to sustain further production of local goods, thus initiating a further downward spiral of economic decline.

There is argument that some studies conducted have put Zimbabwe’s unemployme­nt levels at 10 percent. I have said to my MBA students that, such studies depended on the researcher’s definition of unemployme­nt, where for example selling tomatoes in the streets could have been counted as a form of employment. However, judging from the fiscal challenges that the Government of Zimbabwe is facing, it is clear that de-industrial­isation in Zimbabwe has seriously affected unemployme­nt levels in this country, because there is a correlatio­n between loss of formal employment and reduction in Government taxation revenues. As more companies, especially in the manufactur­ing sector or industry closed down, throwing hundreds of people into the streets, it meant a double or dual reduction or withdrawal in the fiscal revenue contributi­on — bearing in mind that companies on their own are institutio­nal taxation payers, at the same time their employees are individual taxation payers and contributo­rs to the fiscus.

In conclusion, de-industrial­isation in Zimbabwe means that the economy is almost wholly dependent on primary or commodity export earnings, which is not sustainabl­e because of commoditie­s’ vulnerabil­ity to volatility in prices and economic changes in the commoditie­s consuming countries. De-industrial­isation has also affected the country’s ability to substitute imports. We need to think seriously about getting our industries fully functionin­g again.

Dr Bongani Ngwenya is a Bulawayo-based economist and senior lecturer at Solusi University’s Post Graduate School of Business. mailto:ngwenyab@ solusi.ac.zw/ nbongani@gmail.com

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Zimbabwe